Lumping the stimulus and
bailouts together is a mistake
In
“Don’t Look Back in Anger at Bailouts and Stimulus” (WALL STREET JOURNAL, Opinion, Oct. 15, 2015) Alan S.
Blinder and Mark Zandi provide a valuable service by trying to sort out fact
from fiction surrounding steps taken during the financial crisis. They are undoubtedly correct in their
subtitling of their opinion piece: “Without the emergency measures of 2008-09,
the U.S. economy would be far worse off today.”
However, they do a disservice by lumping together monetary policy
initiatives and fiscal policy initiatives and not separating them from
initiatives directed at financial stability.
It pays to look at each separately. Part of the authors’ motive for writing the
opinion piece is the difference between the public's perception of the
initiatives versus the actual impact of the initiatives. Given that focus, it seems reasonable to
start with the initiatives directed toward financial stability since they seem
to be the subject of the most marked misinterpretation.
If one were to pick a poster child for
misinterpretation, it would be TARP.
As such, it can be representative of the initiatives to promote
financial stability. It is worth noting,
however, that TARP was only one of many programs directed toward financial
markets. They range from other asset
purchase programs to extension of FDIC insurance to non-bank liabilities such
as money market funds.
All
of them had as their guiding principle Bagehot’s dictum regarding the
appropriate central bank posture during a financial panic. The dictum is often summarized as lend freely at a high rate
of interest on good banking securities.
Following the dictum is essential to the central bank’s roll as lender
of last resort.
Those who object to the Federal
Reserve's role as a lender of last resort would benefit from a fuller
understanding of the context in which the dictum was developed. The dictum was designed to provide guidance
for ending a financial panic, but quoting it just in that context without
noting the full statement is a disservice.
A more accurate characterization would add “and you are sure to make
money.” One should keep in mind that
when Bagehot wrote LOMBARD STREET: A DESCRIPTION OF THE MONEY
MARKET (1873) he was addressing the operation of the Bank of England which was
a profit-making institution. The advice
was not designed to bailout anyone: it was designed to end panics and make
money in the process.
Consequently, as early as October 2, 2010 it
was possible to write a posting for The Hedged Economist entitled “TARP: A ,success not being acknowledged.” That
posting could cite data that made clear that efforts to ensure financial
stability were far from a bailout.
Clearly, they were going to make money for the US government's Treasury. Those who stick with the bailout terminology
are clearly under the false impression that loans, regardless of the terms,
represent a subsidy of some sort.
Lending money to individuals or organizations who can provide collateral
and pay it back with interest is simply good business, not a subsidy.
Separating out monetary policy also clarifies
who is receiving benefits. Lumping zero
interest rates and quantitative easing in with the TARP loans is absurd. The principal beneficiaries of zero interest
rates and the lower long-term interest rates generated by quantitative easing
can legitimately be described as having been bailed out. They have been bailed out in the sense that
they are the beneficiaries of zero interest rates.
Financial institutions are hardly the major
beneficiaries of zero interest rates.
After all, the regulations under which they operate guarantee that they
will hold a substantial amount of the low-interest government debt. The WALL STREET JOURNAL on 10/15/2015 in an
article entitled “$1.17 Trillion at Zero Percent Interest” pointed out: “Investors
are handing the federal government a lot of free money.” If anyone is being bailed out by zero
interest rates, it is the federal government.
The near zero interest rates give the federal government the option to
borrow the money that they lent to financial institutions at a profit. Granted, the government could just as well
have printed the money, but zero interest rates gave them an additional option.
It would be very easy to lose sight of the
macroeconomic role of monetary policy by pursuing a totally useless witch hunt
for who benefited from zero interest rates.
It is worth noting, however, that it is widely recognized that the
macroeconomic benefits of expansionary monetary policy are often purchased at
the expense of the banking industry. The
banking industry's current net interest margins strongly reinforce the
impression that the benefits of expansionary monetary policy occur despite
their negative impact on the banking industry.
Lumping the financial and monetary policy
initiatives in with the fiscal policy effort is even more unfortunate. The fiscal policy initiatives that spanned
two administrations constitute a mixed bag even when taken alone. The Hedged Economist spent all of September 2010 on postings addressing fiscal policy.
At the time, it was appropriate to refer to them as a failure. But, they were a failure in terms of their
own definitions of success. They were
not a failure in the sense of having no merit.
Alan S. Blinder and Mark Zandi provided one
of the better analyses of the potential impact of the fiscal policy
efforts. At that point, their analysis
was projecting what they felt the impact of the fiscal initiatives would be.
Their
analysis was the subject of postings on the Hedged Economist on 9/15 and
9/28/2010. The postings explained
reasons to believe that they were overestimating the impact.
At the time it seemed they were
overestimating the potential impact. The
reason for feeling that was the case is summarized by the quote below,
especially the portion of the quote highlighted in bold type:
“My concern is that the public will judge the
effectiveness of fiscal stimulus by the Recovery Act. Stimulus started with
Bush's approximately 200 B tax rebates to middle and lower income tax payers.
But, the total over the two administrations is going to come in being well over
a trillion dollars, probably in excess of $10,000 per household. Some partisans
will also stick in any deficit and come up with multiple trillions….From my
perspective, the issue is whether the
multiplier stays linear as the size of the stimulus grows.”
If the quote seems questionable, consider
this: the opinion piece makes a comment that “But it was no coincidence that
the Great Recession ended in June 2009, just four months after the Recovery
Act’s nearly $800 billion-plus stimulus package was passed.” It is clearly falling into the trap of
assessing the fiscal measures as if the Recovery Act was the only fiscal
initiative. Further, while it contends
that it is “no coincidence” that the recession ended four months after the
Recovery Act, it fails to explain how the Recovery Act could produce that
result before it had been implemented.
One does not have to disagree with their
belief that fiscal stimulus contributed to the recovery. Even if one agrees, as I do, that the
beneficial impacts of fiscal policy are real, it is clear that demonstrating
that relationship is far more complicated and subtle than recognizing the
success of financial and monetary policy.
Further, the cost benefits analysis of fiscal stimulus is different from
an acknowledgment that there were some benefits.
Consequently, it would benefit Alan S.
Blinder and Mark Zandi’s efforts to ensure that history gets this right, if
they would focus on the most obvious successes.
That is especially true given that the most obvious success is the
financial stabilization effort, and it is also the one most frequently
mischaracterized as a bailout. Fiscal
stimulus has a natural constituency among liberals. Monetary policy similarly has a constituency
among monetarists. But the only constituency
for the financial stabilization efforts is the facts.
No comments:
Post a Comment