Know
your objective
Why
should an investor be concerned about the chance of a recession?
What
are the implications of the potential recession in 2016?
What
shape would a recession take?
What
risks are implicit in a recession?
Introduction
It seems with the turn of the year there is a ritual
where market observers and investors (they are not the same thing) feel
obligated to prognosticate on the coming year.
For market observers the folly of such forecasting actually makes
sense. Their job, after all, is to
entertain by doing such things. One
thing for sure is that their forecasts may entertain but certainly don't
inform.
A good illustration of that occurred on January 7,
2016 on SeekingAlpha.com. There were two
articles with contrasting forecasts. One
was entitled “2016 Recession Imminent” and the other was entitled “A Happy New Year After All.” They were both
interesting articles with each presenting an argument to support their
contrasting forecasts for 2016. Their
forecasts, in and of themselves, regardless of whether right or wrong, didn't
contain a lot of information useful to investors. Similar contrasting forecast appear in just about
any financial news medium.
By contrast, an investor may try to forecast the
coming year, but the forecast itself is little more than background. Articles like those cited above may be useful
to those who prefer an analysis rather than wading through the raw data to
arrive at their own background forecast.
After all, the investor has to make decisions about the allocation of
resources including the division of cash between immediate consumption and
investment with a view toward future income.
Such decisions are inherently future oriented and thus, whether explicit
or not, they imply a forecast.
However, the implications of the forecast depend
upon the investor’s objectives. Consequently, the same forecast for 2016 can
have markedly different implications for two different investors. The implications can be so markedly different
because of differences in objectives. Of
those differences in objectives, none is more important than differences in the
time horizons of different investors.
With that introduction, it is reasonable to look at
what to expect in 2016, but always from the perspective of what it implies for
people with different sets of objectives.
For those with a very short-term horizon of a year or less, 2016 will be
a year when it is probably better for them to be out of the market. By contrast, those with a 5 to 10 year
horizon can view 2016 as a wonderful opportunity to invest.
An astute reader has probably already realized that
those comments imply a “forecast” of a volatile, down year for the markets in
general. The 22 days since I wrote that
sentence have pretty much eliminated the possibility that it will be
wrong. The year has already demonstrated
volatility and dropped enough to make an up year unlikely. It also should be apparent that those
comments imply a definition of investor that excludes individuals who think
they can rapidly buy and sell in order to profit from short-term (less than a
year) fluctuations.
Besides short-term market timing, there are two other
strategies that will be ignored in the subsequent discussion. They are short selling (including short
selling designed to produce a market neutral portfolio) and various option
strategies. Thus, the discussion that
follows focuses on long-only strategies, and it ignores the potential use of
cash-covered puts and covered calls as a part of the strategies.
Types of recessions
It is important to keep in mind that stock market
cycles and economic cycles are different-but-related phenomena. The timing on stock market cycles and
economic cycles is different. In fact,
stock market cycles are frequently considered as fairly reliable leading
indicators of economic cycles. A closer examination
and consideration of the causality shows that stock market cycles lead certain
economic phenomena and lag other economic phenomena.
Stock performance is ultimately related to the
profitability of the companies one owns by owning equities. Often stocks are portrayed as being priced
based upon future profitability. However,
projections of profitability are based upon both current and historical
information. As a consequence, stock
prices often lag profitability.
The WALL STREET JOURNAL on 8/24/2016 published an article
entitled “Will Spending, Profits Resume Climb?”
It started with the following comment “Profit growth for the
constituents of the S& P 500 index stalled in 2015…” In fact, profits have been declining for two
quarters. Other articles have referred
to it as a profits recession based on the two quarter figure. We are about to go into another earnings
season, and it is unlikely that the trend will be reversed.
Lest one conclude that the phenomena is peculiar to
the larger companies represented in the S&P 500, one should keep in mind
that more small businesses are closing shop than are being started up. Measures of publicly traded small-cap and
mid-cap companies’ profitability also reflect a profits recession. There are also various international surveys
of business climates and the ease of starting a business that show a decline
for the US. So, when populist
politicians seeking the fan envy talk about corporations earning record
profits, like the president did in his State of the Union address, don't take
it as investment advice.
In their book THIS TIME IS DIFFERENT, Carmen
Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff reminded readers of the fact that is all too
obvious to economic historians. No two
recessions are exactly the same. As in
the quote often attributed to Mark Twain, “History never repeats itself, it
only rhymes.” It is particularly
important to understand the difference in the path and financial implications
of the recession brought on by a failure of profit growth versus recessions that
result from a financial crisis. The
implications of liquidity crises are quite different from the implications of
an environment in which the private sector cannot identify ways to produce
general profitability.
A cycle caused by lack of profitable investment
opportunities takes a particular path.
First, profits become harder and harder to produce. Then in response, corporations cut capital
expenditures and entrepreneurs reduce the number of companies starting up. The article cited above reports on both of
these phenomena as follows:
“Expenditures by members of the S& P 500 index
fell in the second and third quarters of 2015 from a year earlier, the first
time since 2010 that the measure has fallen for two consecutive quarters,
according to data from S& P Dow Jones Indices. Another measure of
businesses spending on new equipment—orders for nondefense capital goods,
excluding aircraft—was down 3.6% from a year earlier in the first 11 months of
2015, according to data from the U.S. Department of Commerce.”
“More broadly, only 25% of small companies plan
capital outlays in the next three to six months, according to a November survey
of about 600 firms by the National Federation of Independent Business. That
compares with an average of 29% and a high of 41% since the surveys began in
1974.”
For a while, corporations can maintain reported
profitability by cutting capital expenditures and introducing efficiency
initiatives. In the US, both those
options seem to have run their course.
Once those two opportunities have played out, financial markets have to
respond to the increased risk and reduced profitability. That can take the form of investors selling
assets or just not investing. We have
reached that status of not buying and, in some cases, of actually selling
assets.
Public pensions and mutual funds are holding
increasing amounts of highly liquid short-term assets (i.e., cash). In our words, they are not investing in
long-term assets. Households have
increased their savings rate, and although many commentators can't see past the
reduction in consumption implied by an increased savings rate, viewing it
relative to mutual fund flows shows that households are not using net savings
to invest. They are also keeping it in near
cash form and reducing their debt. Both
the cash and the reduced debt indicate they are increasing their liquidity. Increased capital requirements and the risk
weightings used to determine capital requirements for different types of loans
are inhibiting the free flow of that near cash into productive investment. In an environment where no other sector is
investing in long-term assets, it should not be surprising if corporations are
also retaining more cash and cutting capital expenditures.
The next phase in this type of recession is for
consumers to shift their focus from just not investing to reducing their
consumption. To date, that has taken the
form of a fall in the rate of growth of consumption. The most recent retail sales numbers show an
estimate of virtually no growth and an actual contraction if one removes auto
sales. There is an outside chance that
government retail sales data underestimate sales because they don't adequately
capture the shift from brick-and-mortar retailers to e-commerce. That may introduce more uncertainty, but it
hardly supports an argument that retail sales are still growing. If anything, it would indicate that the
government may be underestimating the falloff in retail sales.
Reports from Nielsen regarding cash register scans
and credit card companies’ reports of transactions (which would include most
e-commerce), all support the notion that retail sales have plateaued or begun
to decline. The notion of a
disappointing holiday season is also consistent with reports from the shipping
companies that handle most e-commerce.
They may have successfully avoided finding themselves with excess
capacity when shipments didn't rise as much is expected. However, the fact that they not only
maintained but actually were ahead of schedule on deliveries would indicate that
the volumes were not as high as they had expected.
Further, there have been numerous reports of
retailers’ over inventoried for the holiday season. In fact, when considering investments in the
retail sector, how the retailer accounts for markdowns in that over inventory can
be an important influence on when they report a contraction in their
margins. Inventory build can temporarily
sustain an economy, but since World War II many mild recessions resulted from
inventory cycles. When inventories are
built in anticipation of growth that actually materializes, they contribute to
growth. But, when inventories build
because of an unanticipated fall off in sales, they contribute to a downturn. Going forward, orders fall off while the
companies involved clear the excess inventory.
To this point, the discussion has been about how
things are developing. But developments
to date can only reflect what could happen.
How they will play out in the future is not predetermined. For example, it is quite possible that
consumers will not respond by cutting consumption. In fact, that would be the forecast of those
who think we will avoid recession. They
would argue based upon current employment developments that consumption will
turn up.
There are number reasons to doubt that employment
will be a good predictor of future consumption.
The first concerns the implications of employment. Consumption is not based upon employment: it
is based upon the wages earned. Wage
data is far less easily interpreted than employment data. The survey and the definitions used to
generate wage data introduce some uncertainty into how to interpret the
data. But, one thing is for sure: wages
are not rising. They may actually even
be falling on average. It isn't until
personal income data is made available that one can verify conclusions based on
wage data.
By looking at the wage component of the personal
income data, one can separate out the wage effect from the other components of
personal income. That exercise is rather
discouraging. The role of wages as a
component of personal income is being decreased by the increasing importance of
property income (rents, interest, dividends, and royalties) and transfer
payments (Social Security and Disability benefits, as well as other components
of the “safety net" such as food stamps, subsidized healthcare, tax
credits, etc.).
One might try to argue that income is income and
this doesn't matter whether increases in personal income are due to the wage
component or some other component. But,
there is a problem with that argument as noted in the December 30, 2015 posting
entitled “’It’s a Wonderful Life’ Rebroadcast.”
It commented: “How many pundits point out that about
two thirds of Gross Domestic Product is represented by consumption? They don't bother to note that it is previous
investment and labor that produces 100% of Gross Domestic Product. One can’t consume what isn't produced.”
In an environment where the incentives to invest in
productivity-improving capital are weak, there may actually be a substitution
effect between wage growth and growth in other components of personal
income. That may be particularly true of
transfer payments since they involve shifting income away from those who
generate output to those who receive the transfer payments. If it discourages work incentives or
investment incentives, such a transfer will manifest itself through lower
productivity and lower wages.
That type of response to incentives would be very
hard to detect. However, there is other
data that would suggest it is occurring.
That other data concerns productivity.
The productivity data is consistent with the notion that wages will not rise
without an increase in capital expenditures.
One should note however the productivity data is derived indirectly from
data in the National Income and Product Accounts (the data used to estimate
Gross Domestic Product). Thus, even
though the data is consistent with this hypothesis, it's worth noting it may be
underestimating.
Previous to the development of National Income and
Product Accounts, economist relied on trade figures and hardgoods output figures
to try to estimate whether the economy was expanding or contracting. As services have become increasingly
important in the economy, the output of goods (manufacturing and mining output)
has become a less reliable measure of overall prosperity. If that were not case, there would be little
doubt that we would currently be assuming we are already in a recession.
Direct output data highlights a contraction, but
that's generally attributed to the shift away from manufacturing. Nevertheless, there is no doubt that there
has been a falloff in trade. Shipping activity in general is falling off. International trade data has been contracting
for a while and the railroads are currently reporting that shipments are
down. That is to be expected. If there is less economic activity, there is
less to ship. Consequently, any
hypothesis that sees employment as a stimulus for growth has to address the
question of whether expanded employment in low productivity, low wage service
sectors can accomplish the task. It can
only accomplish that if it is additional employment as opposed to a substitute
for higher productivity, higher wage manufacturing and mining employment.
The decrease in productivity has occurred simultaneously
with public-sector efforts to try to boost productivity by placing a floor
under the wage component. That's being
done by essentially raising the opportunity costs of employment by placing a
floor under income regardless of whether one is working or not. That increase in the floor below which one
can expect people not to work takes many forms. They range from minimum wages (below which
employment is illegal), subsidized consumption that would be lost if one
increases income (food stamps is a prime example, but welfare payments also
have to be considered since the Obama administration eliminated the work
provisions implemented by the Clinton Administration), and Social Security and
Disability benefits that are structured in a way that discourages work.
While all of these conditions would point to a
downturn, they also would result in it being mild and short-term. The lack of investment discussed above is
being accompanied by a strengthening of the balance sheets of the financial and
corporate sectors. It also means that
households are increasingly liquid. That
liquidity of businesses, financial institutions, and households will eventually
be invested once profitable opportunities arise. It also provides a cushion to absorb
decreases in the value of assets as the recession proceeds. In short, the threshold at which a write-down
of asset values will produce a financial crisis has been raised.
All of these factors discussed above have a negative
economic impact. They will probably
produce a slowdown at a minimum. During
this expansion the economy has experienced a number of slowdowns. They are sometimes attributed to shortcomings
in the way seasonality is handled in the economic data. In other cases, they are attributed to
external shocks (the winter was too cold, winter was too warm, there was
uncertainty about political developments).
In the current environment, shocks such as
cold-weather, warm weather, a political impasse, or an adverse international
development will produce much more than a mild slowdown. Economists often attribute reversals in an
expansion to what is referred to as an external shock. But, external shocks occur all the time: it
is the internal dynamics described above that ensure that this year any
external shock has a high probability of putting the US economy into
recession. The nature of the shock could
make the recession far more severe than the economy’s internal dynamics would
by itself.
Investment implications
It is easy to overestimate the change in behavior
that an investor should make in response to an environment like we are likely
to experience over the next year or two.
As successful investors know, the environment is probably less important
than the investor’s objectives in determining what the appropriate strategy is. At the same time, recessions are usually
accompanied by down stock markets and shouldn't be ignored.
Given the introductory discussion of objectives, the
question is: How should long only investors proceed if their objective is to
build a portfolio that will provide current or future income? In the current environment, three approaches
suggest themselves:
One approach is to dollar-cost average all
investments over the coming year or two.
That approach has the advantage of ensuring that the investor will not
be caught out of the market if the forecast turns out to be wrong. But, it should be undertaken with an
understanding that investments made early in the year may be at higher prices
than are available later in the year. If
it is a down year, investments made during the year will contribute
substantially to future growth in the portfolio. They may not result in immediate growth in
income, but with a 5 to 10 year horizon that is of little consequence. If the investor’s horizon is one year, the
comparable approach is to not invest this year.
A second approach is to not let the economic
environment influence the timing of the investment. Rather, the investor can target acquisitions
in stocks that perform relatively well in such an environment. For example, the widows’ and orphans’
portfolio was discussed in a 2011 blog (“Investing PART 9: One version of the“Unfinished symphony”) and was updated periodically, most notably in the only
blog that discussed actually selling one of the holdings in the portfolio (“TheWidows’ and Orphans’ Portfolio and US Banks”).
If one is building a portfolio like the widows’ and
orphans’ portfolio, it is close to a permanent investment. The current and likely outlook over the
near-term could be used as an opportunity to select from the options implied by
the portfolio.
For example, a down market is a good time to be
adding to the consumer staples category if one wants to reduce volatility
implied by a recession. Companies like
Pepsi, General Mills, Procter & Gamble, Kimberly-Clark, Clorox, and Colgate-Palmolive
mentioned in connection with the widows’ and orphans’ portfolio would be
reasonable additions to the portfolio early in the year. Johnson & Johnson is another firm that
will hold up during an economic downturn.
If one has been building a position in pharmaceutical, medical devices,
or healthcare products companies other than Johnson & Johnson they also may
should hold up well.
By contrast, industrial firms like General Electric,
United Technology, Honeywell, Emerson, Eaton, PPG and 3M would not look like
timely acquisitions until they have come down more in price. If they are acquired early in the year, it
should be done with the understanding that they could go down in value
significantly during the year.
The third approach is to try to expand the portfolio
by adding new names. The diversification
the portfolio provides could be expanded by entering new industries. For example, the only extractive firms
identified in a portfolio are major integrated oil companies. Adding holdings in extractive firms represent
one approach consistent with expanding the portfolio. That approach is tricky since it involves try
to pick the bottom. However, resource cycles
are long. As a consequence, there is no
reason why an investor should feel an obligation to pick the absolute bottom in
the resource cycles. If one sticks the
companies with strong balance sheets, all one loses by not getting the absolute
bottom of the resource cycle is time.
But, with a 5 to 10 year horizon, most resource cycles will have played
out by the intended target date. The
loss from bad timing on resource companies is often the opportunity costs of
having money tied up in equities that are not performing well.
Another approach to adding diversification would be
to acquire a firm in the technology area.
Technology is interesting in that the investor can either try momentum
investments or value investments. If one
needs names, understanding that I tend to be a value investor, I would provide
Microsoft or Intel as examples. But, as
always, investors should do their own research.
In the original widows’ and orphans’ portfolio the
only defense exposure came with Boeing.
Boeing is dominated by commercial aircraft manufacturing. So, if one is looking for defense exposure,
an additional holding may be appropriate.
Both General Dynamics and Lockheed Martin are positioned to experience
performance that will be uncorrelated with the economy.
Another option is to expand into an area that was
briefly mentioned in passing in the original discussion of the widows’ and
orphans’ portfolio. That is fast food
restaurants. My preference there has
been McDonald's, but again, investors may choose either momentum or a value
investment, and investors should, of course, do their own research. By way of disclosure, during McDonald's
difficulties over the last few years I've periodically added to a position in
the company. I'm not sure I would add to
it at current prices, and given the current value of the stock acquired over
the last two years, I'm in the advantageous position of not having to make that
decision. In the original widows’ and
orphans’ portfolio I mentioned Yum brands as an alternative to McDonald's.
The point being, during recessions there are some of
the best opportunities to invest that investors can expect to experience during
an entire lifetime. Recessions provide
an opportunity to buy companies with strong balance sheets, strong franchises,
and healthy cash flows at prices well below their norm. It is very rewarding to purchase a stock when
the company may actually be reporting no current earnings and yet receive an
increase in the dividend based upon management's understanding that the
long-run value of the company is actually increasing.
Successfully approaching the markets during
recessionary periods requires a very well-anchored understanding of one's
objective. It necessitates actions that
properly reflect the investor's disposition toward volatility and willingness
to stick with their chosen time horizon.
Disclosure: The Hedged Economist holds or is planning
to add positions in the stocks mentioned in this posting. They are appropriate for my particular risk
tolerance and investment objectives.
Discussing them does not imply that they would be appropriate for any
other investor.
No comments:
Post a Comment