The news as farce.
One can’t follow the LIBOR “scandal” without
thinking that perhaps you’ve fallen through the looking glass. If you
understand why, you should be singing Gnarl Barkley’s version of Crazy.
To start, one suspects that many of those who are
scandalized do not know what LIBOR is.
So, let’s start with a quick definition.
Basically a bunch of big banks estimate (guess) what they
would have to pay to borrow for various periods of time if they were willing to borrow and if they were borrowing in a well-functioning credit market. For
those who want a more complete and technical definition, an excerpt from the Wikipedia definition is included at the end of this posting.
It seems many
people who comment on the scandal either ignore the definition or can’t
distinguish its important features. They
get hung up on the fact that banks are involved. They miss the fact that it’s a guess about
what the banker could do if the banker lived in a fictional world of
well-functioning markets. The lawsuits surrounding LIBOR reflect just
how absurdly the efficient market theory (EMT) has permeated the thinking of
market non-participants.
Actually EMT is received wisdom when we’re talking about market non-participants. They can’t conceive of a world where EMT doesn’t apply. Yet, to understand the silliness of the LIBOR scandal one must discard EMT completely. It’s folly to judge behavior that can only be assessed if there is a well-functioning market when the behavior occurred at a time when a well-functioning market didn’t exist: put bluntly, the markets weren’t there. There was a liquidity squeeze going on.
The foolishness is
highlighted by the absurdity of thinking banks conspired. Clearly, the herd was in control. That’s what produced the liquidity squeeze in
the first place. A herd doesn’t need to
conspire. It’s a herd for goodness sake!
The absurdity of the conspiracy charge simply ignores how herds function. It is individuals each acting in their own
perceived self-interest that produces the herd.Actually EMT is received wisdom when we’re talking about market non-participants. They can’t conceive of a world where EMT doesn’t apply. Yet, to understand the silliness of the LIBOR scandal one must discard EMT completely. It’s folly to judge behavior that can only be assessed if there is a well-functioning market when the behavior occurred at a time when a well-functioning market didn’t exist: put bluntly, the markets weren’t there. There was a liquidity squeeze going on.
Nevertheless, the
courts will proceed by constructing their own private (and it might be noted
case-specific) counter factual. They’ll
have to guess what a well-functioning market would have looked like. Only then can they decide if each bank’s
behavior, that is its guess, is consistent with the court’s fictional
well-functioning world. They want us to
believe that this financial equivalent of fantasy football will result in
justice. Who are they kidding! Let’s call a shakedown a shakedown.
Another absurdity
is that one branch of government, the judiciary, is assuming it should ignore
the fact that another branch of government, the executive, was proceeding on
the assumption markets had broken down. A
consistent approach would be to throw out any suits that require a different
reality where well-functioning markets had existed. Alternatively one could impeach the executive
branch for pretending markets had broken down.
Just for fun, let’s
assume every bank fudged its estimate to reflect its perceived
self-interest. That is not an
unreasonable assumption. Acting in their
own self is, after all, the charge behind Barclays Bank’s settlement. Could such behavior bias the trimmed mean
average estimate called LIBOR? Only if a
large number of banks had the same perception of their self-interest. That also seems like a reasonable
assumption. As far back as 1776, Adam
Smith pointed out the danger of industry-wide common interests as a part of his
rationale for competitive free trade.
However, looking
closely at the roll of LIBOR raises some serious reasons to set a very high
requirement of proof of a common interest.
To understand why, consider how LIBOR is used. Two major uses are 1) to set the rates on
many variable rate consumer and business loans, and 2) to establish the payouts
and thus the value of many credit derivatives.
The current charge
is that banks systematically underestimated what their borrowing cost would
have been if a market had existed. During
the financial crisis that underestimation made LIBOR appear lower than it
should have been. Given the charge
behind the scandal, it’s reasonable to dismiss the first use of LIBOR as a
justification for the alleged conspiracy.
There haven’t been any convincing arguments supporting the idea that
bankers benefit from artificially low interest rates on consumer and business
loans.
The second use of
LIBOR, as a standard for many financial derivatives, does raise issues. It also raises some doubts: for there to have
been a common perceived self-interest, there would have had to have been a
common net position regarding the derivatives.
Not only is that unlikely, it is probably impossible.
In the derivative
markets, it is often banks that end up holding both sides of the trade. To illustrate, one bank may be strong in
credit cards or HELOCs. It may feel it’s
prudent to swap (or hedge) some of its variable rate loans for a fixed rate
asset. Another bank may be strong in
traditional fixed rate mortgages and want to do just the opposite. When the banks have operations in different
countries such differences can result from something as simple as the borrowing
customs in different countries. Interest
rate SWAPs are a classic derivative. Compound that by multiple currency
exposures that banks may want to swap or hedge.
Add durations, industry or company exposures, etc., and it isn’t
surprising that many derivative trades are ultimately between banks.
While a common
interest may exist, it certainly doesn’t originate from derivative
trading. Derivative trading is more
likely to create conflicting interests.
So, let’s look elsewhere.
Reportedly the
charge in the Barclays settlement is that they intentionally underestimated
what their cost of borrowing would have been.
The charge was they did this to make banks and their bank look healthier
by influencing the price of derivatives called default insurance. Now that seems quite reasonable. They tried
to make themselves look good. What
business, union, government agency, or individual doesn’t? When it’s done to influence a financial
market it can be a serious crime. In
fact, we have numerous regulations to prevent it.
However, here’s the
problem with the conspiracy theory. Why
would other banks want Barclays or the banking sector in general to look good? Were they all insuring Barclays’ debt? Not likely.
To drive home the fact of inconsistent interests, consider whether JP
Morgan had an interest in Bear Sterns looking good before they acquired
it? How about WAMU? Did Wells Fargo want Wachovia to look
good?
Barclays may well
have arrived at an intentionally biased estimate. They may have conspired within the bank or
even gotten other banks to cooperate.
They may have known that their estimates weren’t what they would have
been able to do if they had tried to borrow in a well-functioning market. However, no realistic judgment is possible
without hypothesizing what a well-functioning market would have looked like,
and the terms Barclays would have agreed to.
More likely, Barclays just decided that they just couldn’t win this game
of fantasy football and settling made more sense. We’ll never know. What we do know is that proof only exists on
the other side of the looking glass.
The real wonder
concerning the LIBOR scandal is the self-contradictory posturing of bank
regulators. That’s the topic of the next
posting on LIBOR. Finally, what will
hopefully be the last posting will discuss the good that could result from the
whole farce. “The rate at which an individual Contributor Panel bank could borrow funds, were it to do so by asking for and then accepting inter-bank offers in reasonable market size, just prior to 11.00 London time.”
“This definition is amplified as follows:
- The rate at
which each bank submits must be formed from that bank’s perception of its
cost of funds in the interbank market.
- Contributions
must represent rates formed in London and not elsewhere.
- Contributions
must be for the currency concerned, not the cost of producing one currency
by borrowing in another currency and accessing the required currency via
the foreign exchange markets.
- The rates
must be submitted by members of staff at a bank with primary
responsibility for management of a bank’s cash, rather than a bank’s
derivative book.
- The
definition of “funds” is: unsecured interbank cash or cash raised through
primary issuance of interbank Certificates of Deposit.
“The London Interbank Offered Rate is the
average interest rate estimated by leading banks in London that they would be
charged if borrowing from other banks. It is usually abbreviated to Libor (
/ˈlaɪbɔr/) or LIBOR,
or more officially to BBA Libor
(for British Bankers' Association Libor) or the trademark bbalibor. It is the primary benchmark, along with the Euribor, for short term interest rates around the world….Many
financial institutions, mortgage
lenders and credit card agencies set their own rates relative to it. At least
$350 trillion in derivatives and other
financial products are tied to the Libor. Many financial institutions, mortgage
lenders and credit card agencies set their own rates relative to it. At least
$350 trillion in derivatives and other
financial products are tied to the Libor.”
No comments:
Post a Comment