Prisoners of our history
Introduction
This
first posting on the loss of control is based on a previous posting about the
federal government's debt. The series of postings that will follow this posting
will cover much more than just any single factor. This series of postings is
intended to show the scope of our loss of control of federal expenditures.
Consequently, the debt should be included. Further, the debt is a good place to
start in a highly partisan environment since it is probably the factor in the
loss of control that can be presented with the lowest probability that someone
will mistake the analysis for partisan advocacy. Most people can view debt as a
fact rather than an opinion.
Overview
CBO
reported that the federal budget deficit rose $63 billion in the first half of
fiscal 2017 (October to March) to $522 billion from a year earlier. Those
aren’t estimates; they are actual numbers. But, they were used to introduce CBO
estimates of deficits over the next 10 years. Since the forecast has
implications, it's worth looking at how much value to place on CBO estimates.
Only then does it make sense to look at the substance of their forecasts.
What
looking at the CBO estimates makes clear is the difficulty in interpreting any
forecast. It is highly unlikely that their forecast, or any forecast, will be
realized exactly as predicted. Therefore, much of the discussion that follows
will focus on the forces that influence the outlook rather than any specific
forecast for the outlook. When specific estimates are quoted, they are provided
to show the order of magnitude of the forces involved.
You gotta love
the CBO.
While
the Obama administration was about doubling the national debt over eight years,
the CBO wasn't just low-profile on the issue; in many cases, they actually
obfuscated it. For example, they grossly underestimated the deficit impact of
the stimulus plan. If you think it was a partisan ploy, you might note that
this was done by overestimating its stimulative impact. As I argued in a bunch
of postings in September 2010, every neo-Keynesian was overestimating the
stimulative impact because of flaws in their models. CBO was just particularly
bad.
If
you need another example of CBO's wacko analysis, the Affordable Care Act (ACA)
was estimated to reduce federal deficits by $124 billion by 2019 (March 2010
estimate by the CBO before the law was enacted). They not only got the
magnitude wrong, they got the direction of the impact wrong. Their estimates
were so indefensible that CBO has stopped estimating the effect on the deficit
from the ACA.
It
isn't just economic impacts CBO screws up. In February 2013, CBO predicted that
ACA enrollment in the individual market would be 13 million in 2015, 24 million
in 2016 and 26 million in 2017. The actual enrollments were 11 million, 12
million and initially about 10 million for 2017. The initial 2017 enrollment
was so low the Obama administration extended the enrollment period and launched
an outreach effort which still only got it up to about 12 million, not the 26
million CBO forecast would get coverage thought the ACA’s exchange. As recently
as March 2016, CBO was projecting an enrollment of 15 million for this year. They
were equally flaky on their forecasts for Medicaid.
Similarly,
CBO was also badly wrong about the 2003 Medicare prescription drug benefit. The
drug benefit cost about 40% less over its first decade than CBO projected. You
may recall that this was the unfunded entitlement that was going to destroy the
world.
The
less you think it is a partisan issue, Ryan Lizza in “The Mandate Memo: How
Obama Changed His Mind,” (NewYorker.com, March 26, 2012) reports that Obama
became so frustrated with the CBO that at one point during the healthcare
debate he banned aides from using the term “CBO” in his presence. Instead, he
called the CBO “banana.”
Don't
misunderstand my comment about nonpartisan. I'm not naïve enough to believe
that public employees don't respond to the conflict of interest of being a
public employee when evaluating the impact of public sector activities. I'm
just pointing out that CBO isn't a serious analytical organization. One doesn't
need partisan politics to be incompetent. CBO could be incompetent and partisan,
not just incompetent, but that's a different issue.
The debt is real
and the problem is real
There
is one aspect of CBO’s analysis of the deficit outlook that is free of the conflict
of interest noted above. To some extent, their projection of the deficit is
based upon their assessment of another government organization’s impact, rather
than the impact on the public sector of the private sector. Part of their
projection for growth in the deficit is an assessment of how much the Federal
Reserve (FRB) is going to contribute to the deficit.
The
CBO deficit forecasts are predicated on their own economic growth forecasts as
well as stability in policies. Policies will change, and the CBO is no better
at economic forecasting than anyone else. So, the forecasts themselves are of
less value than their analysis of what's driving the debt and deficit. In some
instances, the impact of CBO forecasts and assumptions are easily isolated. The
impact of the debt on future deficits is one such variable. The impact of the
debt is a product of the size of the debt and the interest-rate the government
pays.
A
logical question is how sensitive are the forecasts to the CBO's assumptions
regarding interest rates. CBO estimates that if interest rates are one
percentage point higher than in its current projections, the result will be
$160 billion additional spending in each year over the next decade. Given that
level of sensitivity and the uncertainties associated with any interest-rate
forecast, current data on the debt and deficit are important to understanding
the forecasts.
The
Federal Government’s net interest payments increased $7 billion in March from a
year earlier. To put that in perspective, the president’s 2018 preliminary
budget proposed cuts of $2.7 billion in discretionary spending. So, the
interest costs increase in one month was almost 3 times what the president was
able to propose cutting in his first year of operations. Further, it's worth
noting that the increase is about 30% for the month. Payments increased by $28
billion for the six months of fiscal 2017 to $152 billion. That is about a 22%
increase, and it is among the biggest increase in a single spending items in
the CBO estimates.
The
increases reflect the larger debt. As
mentioned, the debt has about doubled over the last eight years, but the more ominous
fact is that the growth in the debt accelerated in the last year of the Obama
administration: Federal spending exceeded revenue by $176.2 billion per month
in the closing days of the previous administration. The budget gap was about
$68.2 billion higher than a year ago. For the first six months of the fiscal
year the deficit was about 15% higher than the same period a year earlier. Over
the last 12 months of the administration, the deficit stood at $651.5 billion,
compared to $460.6 billion the year before. Those are Treasury Department
figures not CBO estimates.
The
size and accelerating growth of the debt obviously has implications, but those
implications depend upon one's forecast of interest rates that will be applied
to that debt. For the last eight years
the FRB’s near-zero policy kept Federal government interest rates at historic
lows. That reduced net interest payments even as the overall debt increased. However,
at the same time, the federal fiscal outlook deteriorated due to ever-higher future
interest obligations. In the CBO forecast the Federal Reserve’s decision to
raise interest rates after years of near-zero rates compounds the impact of the
debt.
Raising
interest rates is not the only way the FRB is influencing the deficit forecast.
The FRB’s bond-buying programs earned money. The FRB turned that money over to
Treasury each year, reducing the size of the federal budget deficit by tens of
billions of dollars. FRB officials are indicating that this year they may stop
buying new bonds as those on its balance sheet come due. That will reduce the
number of bonds they have earning interest, and, as a consequence, there will
be smaller FRB contributions to the federal budget. Also, as interest rates
rise, the FRB will have to pay more on bank reserves deposited at the Central Bank.
The FRB pays banks 1% on reserve balances. As the amount the FRB has to pay
banks increases, it will reduce the amount they can turn over to the
government. The amounts aren’t negligible; they pay about $20 billion a year on
reserves.
Thus,
in addition to the higher interest rates that the federal government will have
to pay, there will be a reduction in the more than $90 billion the FRB has
turned over to Treasury in recent years. According to CBO, all of this is set
to explode on President Trump’s watch. One might ask why CBO ignored this time
bomb for so long. After all this is not
the first time they've done 10 year forecasts, and even they aren’t naïve
enough to have assumed that interest rates would never rise. But the more
important point is that the chickens have come home to roost, here-and-now,
according to CBO.
The
FRB is not the only instance where the government pays interest which it then
recovers. According to the Flow of Funds data from the Federal Reserve, about
28% of the federal debt is held on other federal accounts. That includes about
16% of the total federal debt held by the Social Security Trust Fund.
Consequently,
between the FRB which holds 13 to 14% of the debt and the other agencies that
hold about 28%, a significant portion of the federal debt, about 42%, is held
in accounts were some or all of the interest is recovered by the government. Even that 42% estimate understates the total
public-sector ownership of federal government debt. Another 3 – 4% is held by
state and local governments and about 1% is held by the pensions of state and
local governments.
The
fact that close to half the federal government debt is held by the public
sector determines the implication of the rise in the deficit and debt.
Basically, the higher interest payments remove control of how taxes are spent
from the currently-elected federal officials. Some of it is shifted to the
state and local governments that hold the debt. But, the main effect is that it
shifts those revenues to mandated expenditures resulting from the actions of
previous elected officials.
The
interest on debt run up by previous administrations and previous commitments to
programs where expenditures are determined by a formula, independent of revenue,
consume a larger portion of tax revenue. Social Security and Medicare are the
largest such programs, but now they must compete with Affordable Care Act-mandated
expenditures. The fact that the interest cost of the debt rose by three times
as much in one month as the administration was able to cut in its plan for a
year of operations illustrates the loss of control implied. Basically,
elections become irrelevant as currently-elected officials have less and less
control over government priorities. Increasingly, the only option open to an
elected official who wants to control government priorities is to ignore the
deficit, run up the debt, and let the next administration worry about it. That
is a terrible set of incentives.
No comments:
Post a Comment