Don’t
measure it so that you can ignore it
Just
saying “show me the money” doesn't work
A previous posting pointed out that the federal
government does not have a balance sheet. It operates on a cash basis. The
point was made in connection with the discussion of the Medicare and Social
Security trust funds. Those trust funds illustrate one problem created by the
federal government accounting. As ridiculous as it seems, the only asset that
the federal government treats the same way other institutions treat assets is
its own debt. Treating one's own debt as an asset makes no more sense for the
federal government than it would for you or me. Further, the only obligation it
treats as a liability is the national debt. So it's treating its debt as a
liability in some instances, but if it holds that debt, it treats it as an
asset.
The problem with the approach is that owing oneself
money is hardly an asset. Plus, debt is not the only form of a liability. So,
the first step is to identify what is not being taken into account. In some
respects, liabilities are easier to identify. Easier because a major liability
is recognized as the national debt, but even there a more realistic approach
would be to delete that portion of the national debt the federal government
owes to itself.
The national debt, however, is not the only
liability of the federal government. Liabilities are contractual obligations to
future payments. In the case of the federal government, contractual obligation
is a nebulous term. Federal obligations originate from the promises of
politicians when they are written in the law. But even then, laws can be
changed. So the true extent of federal liabilities depends upon one's belief
that the federal government will honor previous commitments.
A common approach and one that is highly useful is
to assume that current laws will not be changed and project the obligations
based on that assumption. The advantage of the approach is that it recognizes
unfunded mandates as liabilities. Some of those mandates have been discussed in
previous postings. Even recognizing them as liabilities only goes halfway to
establishing an accurate accounting for the liability side of the federal
government.
One doesn't need to make a direct promise of payment
in order to create a liability. Liabilities can also be created by guaranteeing
or cosigning on a liability of someone else. In the federal government case,
such liabilities almost always take the form of a guarantee. Essentially, the
federal government is subsidizing the borrower by lending them its good credit
rating. The subsidy has value. But the implied liability has a cost that the
federal government does not recognize. That sets up a terribly perverse
incentive. The federal government treats loan guarantees as if they had no
cost.
There are multiple ways one could go about
estimating the liability implied by the loan guarantee. One appropriate
approach would be to estimate the probability of default on the loans that the
federal government has guaranteed. In the private sector regulated financial
institutions would be required to create a loss reserve to cover that cost.
That reserve would then become an asset that would balance the liability.
Absent a balance sheet no similar procedure exists
for the federal government. However, the federal government could estimate the
loan losses and treat that as if it were the cash outlay in the year the loans
are made. It's unlikely such a procedure would be acceptable since it would
necessitate recognizing that the federal government is making bad loans.
Perhaps a more appropriate approach given the
federal government's practice of doing cash accounting would be to impose the
same charge off rules that are applied to private sector loans. Then as the
loans become delinquent the federal government would have to make it a cash
charge against its budget. That would be an improvement on the current practice
of just allowing the delinquent loan to exist and ignoring the fact that the
federal government (i.e., taxpayers) are going to have to pay it off.
What is being ignored is not trivial. Multiple
previous postings have noted the magnitude of the loans the federal government
is guaranteeing. Most recently there were postings on student loans where the
risks are already in the hundreds of billions of dollars range. However, there
have also been postings on the government's inclination to assume the role as
the leading subprime mortgage lender. The recent financial crisis makes it
impossible to overlook that risk, and it automatically puts the magnitude of
the risk in perspective.
The ability to create liabilities without having to
account for them until they come due encourages financial mismanagement. It
provides an incentive for the government to incur liabilities beyond what would
be considered prudent if they were accounted for properly. But the total
reliance on cash accounting also creates perverse incentives when it comes to
assets.
Cash accounting means that any expenditure whether
for immediate consumption or for a long-lasting asset is accounted for in the
same way. Consequently, if the benefit of investment accrues over 20 years, the
current period return on that investment is only about 1/20 of its lifetime
value. By contrast, any expenditure for current period consumption results in
100% of the value of the expenditure in the current period. Is it any wonder
then that they get expanded food stamps, relaxed qualifications for disability
payments, and subsidies to buy health insurance while infrastructure is allowed
to degenerate. If that seems partisan, I could've used the Medicare
prescription drug plan or a tax cut as examples. The point
is not partisan; the point is there is a structural problem with the incentives
created by cash flow accounting.
At the state level where they have balanced budget
requirements, they also use cash flow accounting. Their solution to the problem
of capital investments is often to borrow specifically for the construction of
a particular capital investment. School bonds are a familiar example. The
effect is to create more congruence between the cash outlay requirements and
the flow of benefits from the capital investment. At the federal level, no
similar procedure is common. Another way to address the issue is to have
separate operating and capital budgets. That creates its own problems, but at
least it makes explicit investment decisions.
The deficiencies of cash flow accounting when assets
are involved doesn't just pertain to investment decisions. It also creates
perverse incentives with regard to managing existing assets. One would have to
be incredibly naïve not to realize that the federal government has tremendous
assets. They include Federal lands, offshore drilling rights, microwave
spectrum, buildings, and in some cases, mineral rights just to name a few.
At any given point those assets can be viewed either
in terms of their current cash value or the stream of benefits they can provide
to Americans over centuries. Just as there is an incentive to focus on the
immediate cash flow when investing, cash flow accounting also encourages the
view of assets as a means of managing current cash flow. Thus, if the budget is
out of balance, an asset can be sold to rectify the cash flow situation. Since
there's no balance sheet, it has no other consequence in terms of the financial
position of the federal government.
The comprehensive balance sheet for the federal
government is an unreasonable request. After all, the greatest asset of the
government is the ability to tax. Determining that would involve speculating on
the attitude of future populations toward taxes. Nevertheless, the net effect
of cash flow accounting is to encourage the natural propensity of politicians
to have a short-term focus coinciding with their reelection cycles.
Cash flow management is an important aspect of
financial management, but it isn't a blueprint for a complete view of
appropriate financial management. At a minimum, the federal government should
try to estimate those aspects of the balance sheet that can be subjected to
reasonable accounting rules.
However, far more important than trying to apply
private sector accounting rules to the federal government is getting elected
officials to think in terms of a balance sheet rather than election cycles. Elected
officials are only part of the problem; executive employees, the bureaucrats,
need to think in terms of the balance sheet rather than processes and
throughput. After all, various federal agencies have tried applying private
sector accounting practices with almost no improvement in performance.
No comments:
Post a Comment